전체기사 최신뉴스 GAM
KYD 디데이
글로벌

속보

더보기

도널드 콘 '테일러 준칙' 연설 원문(영문)

기사입력 : 2007년10월13일 12:39

최종수정 : 2007년10월13일 12:39

※ 본문 글자 크기 조정

  • 더 작게
  • 작게
  • 보통
  • 크게
  • 더 크게

※ 번역할 언어 선택

Vice Chairman Donald L. Kohn
At the Conference on John Taylor's Contributions to Monetary Theory and Policy, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, Dallas, Texas
October 12, 2007

John Taylor Rules

The Role of Simple Rules in Monetary Policymaking
It is a pleasure and an honor to speak at this conference honoring John Taylor and his contributions to monetary theory and policy. As you have already heard from Chairman Bernanke and the other speakers today, John has made a number of seminal contributions to the field of macroeconomics. What has distinguished John's work, in my view, is that he takes policymaking in the real world seriously.1

Taking policymaking seriously involves understanding the constraints imposed on our decisions by partial information and incomplete knowledge of economic relationships. It also implies the use of empirically valid models that acknowledge the efforts of households and businesses to anticipate the future and maximize their welfare over time. In the late 1980s and early 1990s, macroeconomics was focused mainly on real business cycles and endogenous growth theory. During this period, John was one of a very small number of academic economists who continued to pursue research aimed at informing the conduct of monetary policy. John's Carnegie Rochester conference paper published in 1993 is an excellent example of this research.

Importantly, John's legacy to the Federal Reserve has not been confined to enhancing our understanding of monetary policy. In addition, he has turned out legions of students who have followed in his footsteps in their interest in policy. Many of them have spent time in the Federal Reserve, producing a rich array of contributions to policymaking and research.

John and I have spent countless hours discussing how the Federal Reserve arrives at decisions about monetary policy and how it should arrive at decisions. Those conversations began in earnest in the late 1980s, when John was on the Council of Economic Advisers, and they have continued to the present day. They have occurred not only in offices and classrooms in Washington and Stanford and at numerous conferences around the globe, but also around dinner tables in Washington and Palo Alto and on hiking trails from Vermont to Wyoming. Those conversations made me a better policy adviser and then policymaker, and they have had the added and very special bonus of allowing Gail and me to count John and Allyn among our friends. I can't think of a better way to honor John's contributions than to continue that discussion around the dinner tables of Dallas by reflecting on the role of simple rules in informing policymaking.

Three Benefits of Simple Rules in Monetary Policymaking
In his Carnegie Rochester conference paper, John considered a simple policy rule under which the nominal federal funds rate is adjusted in response to both the gap between real and trend gross domestic product (GDP) and the gap between the inflation rate and policymakers' target. Based on data for the previous few years, John calibrated the long-run target for inflation and the two parameters that determine the responsiveness of the federal funds rate to the two gaps. The equilibrium real interest rate was based on a longer history of actual real interest rates. In the handout, Figure 1A depicts the actual nominal funds rate and the Taylor rule prescriptions between 1987 and 1992, as presented in John's paper. Despite its simplicity, this policy rule fits the data remarkably well; it described a period of generally successful policymaking; and it adhered to the Taylor principle of adjusting the nominal rate more than one-for-one with changes in the inflation rate, so it provided a plausible template for future success. It is no wonder that John has been such a dedicated salesman and that his efforts have been so well received in academia and policy councils.



Following John's seminal contribution, many other economists have engaged in research on similar policy rules and, together with John, have identified several benefits of such rules in conducting monetary policy. I will elaborate on three of them.

The first benefit of looking at a simple rule like John's is that it can provide a useful benchmark for policymakers. It relates policy setting systematically to the state of the economy in a way that, over time, will produce reasonably good outcomes on average. Importantly, the emphasis is on levels and gaps, not growth rates, as inputs to the policy process. This emphasis can be a problem when a level, say of potential GDP, is in question, but in many respects it is also a virtue. For the United States, the two gaps relate directly to the legislative mandate of the Federal Reserve to achieve stable prices and maximum employment. Moreover, those two gaps fit directly into most modern macroeconomic theories, which tell us something about their relationship and how that relationship can be affected by the type of shock hitting the economy.

Model uncertainties make the simplicity of the rule particularly important for the policymaker because research suggests that the prescriptions from simple rules can be more robust than optimal-control policies. Optimal-control policies can depend critically on the exact specification of the model, and clearly there is no consensus about which model best describes the U.S. economy.

Federal Reserve policymakers are shown several versions of Taylor rules in the material we receive before each meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC). I always look at those charts and tables and ask myself whether I am comfortable with any significant deviation of my policy prescription from those of the rules.

A second benefit of simple rules is that they help financial market participants form a baseline for expectations regarding the future course of monetary policy. Even if the actual policy process is far more sophisticated than any simple rule could completely describe, the rule often provides a reasonably good approximation of what policymakers decide and a framework for thinking about policy actions. Indeed, many financial market participants have used the Taylor rule to understand U.S. monetary policy over the past fifteen years. Investors and other market participants are going to form expectations about policy and act on those expectations. The more accurate and informed those expectations are, the more likely are their actions to reinforce the intended effects of policy.

A third benefit is that simple rules can be helpful in the central bank's communication with the general public. Such an understanding is important for the transmission mechanism of monetary policy. Giving the public some sense of how the central bank sees the output and inflation gaps and how they are expected to evolve will help it understand the central bank's objectives and how policymakers are likely to respond to surprises in incoming data.

Four Limitations of Simple Rules
Simple rules have limitations, of course, as benchmarks for monetary policy. To quote from John's Carnegie Rochester paper, "a policy rule can be implemented and operated more informally by policymakers who recognize the general instrument responses that underlie the policy rule, but who also recognize that operating the rule requires judgment and cannot be done by computer" (p. 198). In that context, four limitations of simple rules are important.

The first limitation is that the use of a Taylor rule requires that a single measure of inflation be used to obtain the rule prescriptions. The price index used by John in the Carnegie Rochester paper was the GDP price deflator. Other researchers have used the inflation measure based on the consumer price index (CPI). Over the past fifteen years, the Federal Reserve has emphasized the inflation rate as measured by changes in the price index for personal consumption expenditures (PCE). Many researchers have also explored the use of core price indexes, which exclude the volatile food and energy components, as better predictors of future inflation or as more robust indicators of the sticky prices that some theories say should be the targets of policy. To be sure, over long periods, most of these measures behave very similarly. But policy is made in the here and now, and the various indexes can diverge significantly for long stretches, potentially providing different signals for the appropriate course of monetary policy.

Second, the implementation of the Taylor rule and other related rules requires determining the level of the equilibrium real interest rate and the level of potential output; neither of them are observable variables, and both must be inferred from other information. John used 2 percent as a rough guess as to the real federal funds rate that would be consistent with the economy producing at its potential. But the equilibrium level of the real federal funds rate probably varies over time because it depends on factors such as the growth rate of potential output, fiscal policy, and the willingness of savers to supply credit to households and businesses. Inaccurate estimates of this rate will mislead policymakers about the policy stance required to achieve full employment. In a similar vein, real-time estimates of potential output can be derived in a number of ways and--as shown by Orphanides (2003) and others--they are subject to large and persistent errors. If policymakers inadvertently rely on flawed estimates, they will encounter persistent problems in achieving their inflation objective.

The third limitation of using simple rules for monetary policymaking stems from the fact that, by their nature, simple rules involve only a small number of variables. However, the state of a complex economy like that of the United States cannot be fully captured by any small set of summary statistics. Moreover, policy is best made looking forward, that is, on the basis of projections of how inflation and economic activity may evolve. Lagged or current values of the small set of variables used in a given simple rule may not provide a sufficient guide to future economic developments, especially in periods of rapid or unusual change. For these reasons, central banks monitor a wide range of indicators in conducting monetary policy. In his Carnegie Rochester paper, John mentioned the stock market crash of October 1987 as an example of how other variables can and should influence the course of monetary policy in some situations.

The final limitation I want to highlight is that simple policy rules may not capture risk-management considerations. In some circumstances, the risks to the outlook or the perceived costs of missing an objective on a particular side may be sufficiently skewed that policymakers will choose to respond by adjusting policy in a way that would not be justified solely by the current state of the economy or the modal outlook for output and inflation gaps.

Policy Rules around 2003
Some of the ambiguities and potential pitfalls in the use of simple policy rules are highlighted by considering their prescriptions for a period earlier in this decade. Turning to Figure 1B, the solid line indicates the actual federal funds rate between the first quarter of 1993 and the second quarter of 2007, and the dashed line shows the prescriptions of the Taylor rule using the same methodology that John used in his Jackson Hole remarks this year.2 For the earlier part of the sample, the prescription from this simple rule tracks the actual funds rate relatively well. As John pointed out, a notable deviation happened beginning in 2002, and I would like to discuss that period to illustrate the limitations I noted earlier.



Inflation Measure
The first limitation is related to the measure used for the inflation variable included in the rules. The rule prescriptions depicted by the dashed line in Figure 1B are based on the headline CPI. But as you know, the FOMC often looks at core inflation, stripping out the effects of energy and food prices, as a better indicator of future price behavior. The dotted line represents the rule prescriptions based on the chain-weighted core CPI, which the Bureau of Labor Statistics has produced since 2000. Using this measure lowers the prescribed funds rate by about 2 percentage points during 2003, bringing the rule prescriptions much closer to the actual path of policy. The reason for the improvement is evident from Figure 2A, on the other side of the handout: Even though the headline and core CPI measures were broadly similar in the mid- to late 1990s, these measures diverged substantially between 2003 and 2005.


Potential Output
The second limitation relates to the challenge of judging the level of potential output in real time. To illustrate this point, Figure 2B plots three measures of the output gap. The solid line is the real-time estimate by the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) that was used in the Taylor rule prescriptions in Figure 1B, while the dashed line depicts the CBO's ex post estimate of the output gap as of the third quarter of 2007. Back in 2003, the CBO estimated that output at that time was below potential by only 1 percent. With the benefit of four more years of data, the CBO currently estimates that the output gap for the first half of 2003 was considerably wider--about 3 percent. In addition, the dotted line represents an alternative measure of resource utilization derived from the unemployment rate and an estimate of the natural rate of unemployment (NAIRU) taken from the Board staff's FRB/US model. In fact, the unemployment rate was rising through the middle of 2003, so the FOMC had every reason to believe that the output gap was widening at that time. Using this unemployment-based measure rather than the real-time CBO measure would reduce the prescriptions of simple policy rules by roughly 1/2 percentage point in early 2003.


Other Variables
The third limitation in my list was that the small set of economic measures included in simple rules may not fully reflect the state of the economy. Around 2003, financial market conditions may not have been adequately summarized by the assumed 2 percent equilibrium federal funds rate. Accounting scandals caused economic agents to lose confidence in published financial statements and in bond ratings. The result was higher uncertainty about the financial health of firms, and credit spreads widened substantially. Figure 2C shows that risk spreads on corporate bonds were elevated in this period. Other things equal, such spreads would reduce the federal funds rate needed to achieve full employment, perhaps explaining a portion of the gap between the actual federal funds rate and the outcome from the policy rule during this period.


Risk Management
The last item on my list of limitations was that simple rules do not take account of risk-management considerations. As shown in Figure 2A, the core CPI inflation rate for 2003 was falling toward 1 percent. The real-time reading of the core PCE inflation rate (not shown) was on average even lower than the comparable CPI figure. Given these rates, the possibility of deflation could not be ruled out. We had carefully analyzed the Japanese experience of the early 1990s; our conclusion was that aggressively moving against the risk of deflation would pay dividends by reducing the odds on needing to deal with the zero bound on nominal interest rates should the economy be hit with another negative shock. This factor is not captured by simple policy rules.

A Final Note
I have offered this analysis in the spirit of so many of the discussions I have had with John. His framework has been enormously important to policymaking in the Federal Reserve, and it has yielded many benefits. Nevertheless, it's important to keep in mind that some significant practical limitations also are associated with the application of such rules in real time. In other words, it's not so simple to use simple rules!

References
Orphanides, Athanasios (2003). "The Quest for Prosperity without Inflation," Leaving the Board Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 50 (April), pp. 633-63.

Poole, William (2007). "Understanding the Fed (210 KB PDF)," Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Review, vol. 89 (January/February), pp. 3-14, http://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/review/past/2007.

Taylor, John B. (1993). "Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice," Leaving the Board Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 39, pp. 195-214, http://econpapers.repec.org/article/eeecrcspp/default1993.htm.

_________ (2007). "Housing and Monetary Policy (244 KB PDF)," speech delivered at "Housing, Housing Finance, and Monetary Policy," a symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, held in Jackson Hole, Wyo., August 30-September 1, www.kansascityfed.org/publicat/sympos/2007/pdf/2007.09.04.Taylor.pdf.

Footnotes

1. I am sure my colleagues join me in honoring John. However, my thoughts on policy rules are my own and not necessarily those of my colleagues on the Federal Open Market Committee. Jinill Kim and Andrew Levin, of the Board's staff, contributed to the preparation of these remarks.

2. Following John, the rule specification and the data used for the prescriptions closely follow the implementation of the Taylor rule in Bill Poole's speech in August 2006 (Poole, 2007). The inflation measure used for this rule is the four-quarter average headline CPI inflation rate, with the benchmark value set to 2 percent. Through 2001, the gap between real GDP and its potential is the value measured in real time by the staff of the Board of Governors. Because subsequent staff estimates of the output gap are not yet publicly available, the rule prescriptions for the post-2001 period are computed with the real-time output gap as constructed by the Congressional Budget Office.

[뉴스핌 베스트 기사]

사진
李정부, 123개 국정과제 공식 확정 [세종=뉴스핌] 양가희 기자 = 정부가 향후 5년간 국정 운영의 핵심 로드맵이 될 123대 국정과제를 본격 추진한다. 정부는 16일 정부세종청사에서 국무회의를 열고 국정과제를 포함한 국정과제 관리계획을 확정했다고 밝혔다. 국무회의에서 확정된 123대 국정과제는 지난달 13일 국정기획위원회에서 제안한 '이재명 정부 국정운영 5개년 계획(안)'을 정부 차원의 검토 및 조정·보완을 거쳐 확정한 것이다. 이재명 대통령이 16일 오전 취임 후 처음으로 정부세종청사에서 국무회의를 직접 주재하면서 국가균형발전에 대한 발언을 하고 있다. [사진=KTV] 최종 확정된 국정과제 체계는 '국민이 주인인 나라, 함께 행복한 대한민국'이라는 국가비전 아래 5대 국정목표, 23대 추진전략, 123대 과제로 구성됐다. 5대 국정목표는 ▲국민이 하나되는 정치 ▲세계를 이끄는 혁신경제 ▲모두가 잘사는 균형성장 ▲기본이 튼튼한 사회 ▲국익 중심의 외교안보다. 우선 정부는 국민주권 실현 및 대통령 책임 강화를 위한 개헌을 추진한다. 4년 연임제 및 결선투표제 도입, 감사원 국회 소속 이관, 대통령 거부권 제한, 국무총리 국회추천제 도입 등이 개헌안에 담길 전망이다. 권력기관 개혁을 통한 민주주의 확립, 독자 인공지능(AI) 생태계 및 AI고속도로 구축, 5극3특 중심 혁신·일자리 거점 조성, 경제협력개발기구(OECD) 수준 산재 감축 등의 내용도 국정과제에 담겼다. 또 이재명 정부 임기 내 전시작전통제권 전환을 완료하는 강군 육성 방안도 포함됐다. 행정수도 세종 완성과 2차 공공기관 이전도 차질없이 진행할 계획이다.  이재명 대통령이 16일 오전 취임 후 처음으로 정부세종청사에서 국가균형발전 관련 국무회의를 직접 주재하고 있다. [사진=KTV] 국정과제 이행을 위한 범정부 추진체계도 구축한다. 온라인 국정관리시스템과 오프라인 범부처 협의체를 운영, 국정과제 추진상황을 지속 관리한다. 입법성과 조기 창출을 위해 법제처에 국정입법상황실을 두고, 국정과제 입법 전주기를 밀착 관리한다. 국정과제 중 입법조치가 필요한 사항은 법률 751건, 하위법령 215건 등 총 966건으로 나타났다. 이 중 법률안 110건은 연내 국회 제출하고, 하위법령 66건 올해 제·개정한다는 계획이다. 국정과제 추진과정에서 국민과의 소통을 강화하고, 정책성과를 국민이 실질적으로 체감할 수 있도록 한다. 온라인 소통창구인 '국정과제 소통광장'을 마련, 국민이 제기한 의견을 정부가 신속히 답하는 쌍방향 소통채널을 만든다. 국민만족도 조사는 주기적으로 실시하고 민생 관련 중요 국정과제는 민관합동 현장점검을 실시한다. 국정과제 추진성과를 평가하기 위한 '정부업무평가 기본계획('25~'27)' 및 '2025년도 정부업무평가 시행계획 수정안'도 이날 국무회의에서 확정됐다. 올해는 미래 전략산업 육성 등 각 부처가 역점 추진하는 정책과제, 신산업 등 규제 합리화, AI 활용 일하는 방식 혁신, 디지털 소통·홍보 노력 강화 등을 중점 평가할 예정이다. 국민주권정부에 걸맞게 평가 과정에 국민 참여를 확대하고, 국민 만족도 조사 결과도 비중 있게 반영한다. 국무조정실은 "향후 국정과제 추진과정에서 국민의견을 수시로 청취하고 소통을 강화해 나갈 예정"이라며 "국민요구와 정책여건 변화를 반영해 이행계획도 지속 보완하며 추진할 계획"이라고 밝혔다. sheep@newspim.com 2025-09-16 14:04
사진
코어위브, 엔비디아와 8조원대 계약 [서울=뉴스핌]박공식 기자 = 데이터센터 운영업체인 코어위브(종목코드: CRWV)는 인공지능(AI) 칩 선두 주자 엔비디아와 63억 달러(8조7160억원) 규모의 클라우드 컴퓨팅 용량 주문 계약을 체결했다고 15일(현지시간) 밝혔다. 엔비디아는 이번 계약을 통해 2032년 4월 13일 까지 코어위브가 고객에게 판매하지 않은 모든 클라우드 용량을 구매하기로 했다. 엔비디아와 수주 계약 체결 소식이 전해진 후 코어위브 주가는 뉴욕 정규장 거래에서 8% 상승했다. 지난 3월 상장 이후 이 회사 주가는 3배 뛰었다. 코어위브는 미국과 유럽에서 엔비디아의 GPU 칩을 탑재한 대규모 데이터센터를 운영하며 이를 임대하거나 클라우드 컴퓨팅 용량을 판매하고 있다. 이번 계약으로 코어위브는 엔비디아의 핵심 클라우드 파트너로서의 입지를 공고히 하고 AI 컴퓨팅 용량 수요 감소 가능성에 대한 완충장치를 마련하게 됐다고 로이터 통신은 평가했다. 코어위브는 일찌감치 엔비디아의 눈도장을 받아 2023년 투자를 받았다. 엔비디아는 코어위브 지분을 6% 넘게 보유하고 있다. 코어위브는 지난 3월 공모가 40달러에 뉴욕 증시에 상장한 후 AI 열풍에 따른 클라우드 서비스 수요 급증에 힘입어 주가가 급등했다. 투자은행 바클레이즈는 "이번 계약은 최종 고객과 상관없이 용량이 활용될 것을 보장함으로써 코어위브의 안전장치 역할을 한다"며 "투자자들은 코어위브가 최대 고객사 2곳(마이크로소프트와 오픈AI) 외에 데이터센터 용량을 채울 수 있을지 우려해왔는데, 이번 계약으로 이런 우려가 사라졌다"고 분석했다.  코어위브 로고 [서울=뉴스핌]박공식 기자 = 2025.09.16 kongsikpark@newspim.com 코어위브는 지난 3월 챗GPT 개발사 오픈AI와 119억 달러 규모의 5년 계약에 합의하며, 클라우드 컴퓨팅 용량을 제공하기로 한 바 있다. 오픈AI는 2029년 4월까지 40억 달러까지 지급하기로 약속하는 추가 협정을 맺었다. kongsikpark@newspim.com 2025-09-16 13:03
기사 번역
결과물 출력을 준비하고 있어요.
기사제목
기사가 번역된 내용입니다.
종목 추적기

S&P 500 기업 중 기사 내용이 영향을 줄 종목 추적

결과물 출력을 준비하고 있어요.

긍정 영향 종목

  • Lockheed Martin Corp. Industrials
    우크라이나 안보 지원 강화 기대감으로 방산 수요 증가 직접적. 미·러 긴장 완화 불확실성 속에서도 방위산업 매출 안정성 강화 예상됨.

부정 영향 종목

  • Caterpillar Inc. Industrials
    우크라이나 전쟁 장기화 시 건설 및 중장비 수요 불확실성 직접적. 글로벌 인프라 투자 지연으로 매출 성장 둔화 가능성 있음.
이 내용에 포함된 데이터와 의견은 뉴스핌 AI가 분석한 결과입니다. 정보 제공 목적으로만 작성되었으며, 특정 종목 매매를 권유하지 않습니다. 투자 판단 및 결과에 대한 책임은 투자자 본인에게 있습니다. 주식 투자는 원금 손실 가능성이 있으므로, 투자 전 충분한 조사와 전문가 상담을 권장합니다.
안다쇼핑
Top으로 이동