전체기사 최신뉴스 GAM
KYD 디데이
글로벌

속보

더보기

버냉키, '금융 가속기와 신용채널' 주제 연설(원문)

기사입력 : 2007년06월17일 18:57

최종수정 : 2007년06월17일 18:57

Remarks by Chairman Ben S. Bernanke
At a conference on The Credit Channel of Monetary Policy in the Twenty-first Century, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Atlanta, Georgia
June 15, 2007

The Financial Accelerator and the Credit Channel

Economic growth and prosperity are created primarily by what economists call "real" factors--the productivity of the workforce, the quantity and quality of the capital stock, the availability of land and natural resources, the state of technical knowledge, and the creativity and skills of entrepreneurs and managers. But extensive practical experience as well as much formal research highlights the crucial supporting role that financial factors play in the economy. An entrepreneur with a great new idea for building a better mousetrap typically must tap financial capital, perhaps from a bank or a venture capitalist, to transform that idea into a profitable commercial enterprise. To expand and modernize their plants and increase their staffs, most firms must turn to financial markets or to financial institutions to secure this essential input. Families rely on the financial markets to obtain mortgages or to help finance their children's educations. In short, healthy financial conditions help a modern economy realize its full potential. For this reason, one of the critical priorities of developing economies is establishing a modern, well-functioning financial system. In the United States, a deep and liquid financial system has promoted growth by effectively allocating capital and has increased economic resilience by increasing our ability to share and diversify risks both domestically and globally.

Just as a healthy financial system promotes growth, adverse financial conditions may prevent an economy from reaching its potential. A weak banking system grappling with nonperforming loans and insufficient capital or firms whose creditworthiness has eroded because of high leverage or declining asset values are examples of financial conditions that could undermine growth. Japan faced just this kind of challenge when the financial problems of banks and corporations contributed substantially to sub-par growth during the so-called "lost decade."

As the topic of this conference reminds us, financial conditions may affect shorter-term economic conditions as well as the longer-term health of the economy. Notably, some evidence supports the view that changes in financial and credit conditions are important in the propagation of the business cycle, a mechanism that has been dubbed the "financial accelerator." Moreover, a fairly large literature has argued that changes in financial conditions may amplify the effects of monetary policy on the economy, the so-called credit channel of monetary-policy transmission. In fact, as I will discuss, these two ideas are essentially related. As someone who (in a former life) did research on both of these topics, I thought it might be useful for me to provide a somewhat personal overview of the financial accelerator and credit channel ideas and their common underlying logic. Along the way I will offer a few thoughts on where future research might be most productive.

Market Frictions and the Real Effects of Financial and Credit Conditions
Economists have not always fully appreciated the importance of a healthy financial system for economic growth or the role of financial conditions in short-term economic dynamics. As a matter of intellectual history, the reason is not difficult to understand. During the first few decades after World War II, economic theorists emphasized the development of general equilibrium models of the economy with complete markets; that is, in their analyses, economists generally abstracted from market "frictions" such as imperfect information or transaction costs. But without such frictions, financial markets have little reason to exist. For example, with complete markets (and if we ignore taxes), we know that whether a corporation finances itself by debt or equity is irrelevant (the Modigliani-Miller theorem).

The blossoming of work on asymmetric information and principal-agent theory, led by Nobel laureates Joseph Stiglitz and George Akerlof and with contributions from many other researchers, gave economists the tools to think about the central role of financial markets in the real economy. For example, the classic 1976 paper by Michael Jensen and William Meckling showed that, in a world of imperfect information and principal-agent problems, the capital structure of the firm could be used as a tool by shareholders to better align the incentives of managers with the shareholders' interests. Thus was born a powerful and fruitful rejoinder to the Modigliani-Miller neutrality result and, more broadly, a perspective on capital structure that has had enduring influence.

My own first job as an academic was at Stanford University, where I arrived as an assistant professor in the Graduate School of Business in 1979. At the time, Stanford was a hotbed of work on asymmetric information, incentives, and the principal-agent problem; and even though my field was macroeconomics, I was heavily influenced by that intellectual environment. I became particularly interested in how this perspective on financial markets could help explain why financial crises--that is, extreme disruptions of the normal functioning of financial markets--seem often to have a significant impact on the real economy. Putting the issue in the context of U.S. economic history, I laid out, in a 1983 article, two channels by which the financial problems of the 1930s may have worsened the Great Depression (Bernanke, 1983).

The first channel worked through the banking system. As emphasized by the information-theoretic approach to finance, a central function of banks is to screen and monitor borrowers, thereby overcoming information and incentive problems. By developing expertise in gathering relevant information, as well as by maintaining ongoing relationships with customers, banks and similar intermediaries develop "informational capital." The widespread banking panics of the 1930s caused many banks to shut their doors; facing the risk of runs by depositors, even those who remained open were forced to constrain lending to keep their balance sheets as liquid as possible. Banks were thus prevented from making use of their informational capital in normal lending activities. The resulting reduction in the availability of bank credit inhibited consumer spending and capital investment, worsening the contraction.

The second channel through which financial crises affected the real economy in the 1930s operated through the creditworthiness of borrowers. In general, the availability of collateral facilitates credit extension. The ability of a financially healthy borrower to post collateral reduces the lender's risks and aligns the borrower's incentives with those of the lender. However, in the 1930s, declining output and falling prices (which increased real debt burdens) led to widespread financial distress among borrowers, lessening their capacity to pledge collateral or to otherwise retain significant equity interests in their proposed investments. Borrowers' cash flows and liquidity were also impaired, which likewise increased the risks to lenders. Overall, the decline in the financial health of potential borrowers during the Depression decade further impeded the efficient allocation of credit. Incidentally, this information-based explanation of how the sharp deflation in prices in the 1930s may have had real effects was closely related to, and provided a formal rationale for, the idea of "debt-deflation," advanced by Irving Fisher in the early 1930s (Fisher, 1933).

The External Finance Premium and the Financial Accelerator
Both real and monetary shocks produced the Great Depression, and in my 1983 paper I argued that banking and financial markets propagated both types of impulses, without distinguishing sharply between the two. My subsequent research and that of many others looked separately at the role of financial conditions in amplifying both monetary and nonmonetary influences.

On the nonmonetary side, Mark Gertler and I showed how, in principle, the effects of a real shock (such as a shock to productivity) on financial conditions could lead to persistent fluctuations in the economy, even if the initiating shock had little or no intrinsic persistence (Bernanke and Gertler, 1989). A key concept in our analysis was the external finance premium, defined as the difference between the cost to a borrower of raising funds externally and the opportunity cost of internal funds. External finance (raising funds from lenders) is virtually always more expensive than internal finance (using internally generated cash flows), because of the costs that outside lenders bear of evaluating borrowers' prospects and monitoring their actions. Thus, the external finance premium is generally positive. Moreover, the theory predicts that the external finance premium that a borrower must pay should depend inversely on the strength of the borrower's financial position, measured in terms of factors such as net worth, liquidity, and current and future expected cash flows. Fundamentally, a financially strong borrower has more "skin in the game," so to speak, and consequently has greater incentives to make well-informed investment choices and to take the actions needed to ensure good financial outcomes. Because of the good incentives that flow from the borrower's having a significant stake in the enterprise and the associated reduction in the need for intensive evaluation and monitoring by the lender, borrowers in good financial condition generally pay a lower premium for external finance.1

The inverse relationship of the external finance premium and the financial condition of borrowers creates a channel through which otherwise short-lived economic shocks may have long-lasting effects. In the hypothetical case that Gertler and I analyzed, an increase in productivity that improves the cash flows and balance sheet positions of firms leads in turn to lower external finance premiums in subsequent periods, which extends the expansion as firms are induced to continue investing even after the initial productivity shock has dissipated. This "financial accelerator" effect applies in principle to any shock that affects borrower balance sheets or cash flows. The concept is useful in that it can help to explain the persistence and amplitude of cyclical fluctuations in a modern economy.

Although the financial accelerator seems intuitive--certainly financial and credit conditions tend to be procyclical--nailing down this mechanism empirically has not proven entirely straightforward. For example, empirical studies of business investment in structures, equipment, and inventories have often found that a firm's cash flow significantly determines its level of investment and that the link between cash flow and investment tends to be stronger for firms (such as relatively small firms) that have more limited access to capital markets.2 In a "frictionless" capital market in which borrowers do not face an external finance premium, a firm's cash position would be irrelevant to its decision to invest because efficient capital markets would supply any necessary funding for investment projects expected to yield a positive net return. Thus, findings of a positive association between cash flow and investment tends to support the financial accelerator theory.

These findings also raise issues and questions, however. I will mention two. First, as a number of researchers have pointed out, the apparent empirical link between cash flow and investment may arise because cash flow proxies for difficult-to-measure factors like the prospective return on investment, which would be relevant to the investment decision even without capital-market frictions. This identification problem is a difficult one. However, some work that has attempted to correct for this possible misspecification has still found a role for cash flow (see, for example, Gilchrist and Himmelberg, 1999). Second, if only the smallest firms have significant external finance premiums, as implied by some research, then the macroeconomic significance of the financial accelerator may be questioned. One response to this point, pursued by several researchers, has been to dispute the claim that small firms do not play a significant role in business-cycle fluctuations. For example, small firms apparently account for a significant portion of cyclical changes in employment and inventory stocks. Another response has been to argue that even large firms with relatively good access to capital markets may face nontrivial external finance premiums. For instance, using a sample that included large public companies, researchers at the Board have estimated external finance premiums of economically significant magnitudes, and they showed that these premiums rose sharply during the 2001 recession, as predicted by the financial accelerator theory (Levin, Natalucci, and Zakrajsek, 2004; Levin and Natalucci, 2005).

Financial accelerator effects need not be confined to firms and capital spending but may operate through household spending decisions as well.3 Household borrowers, like firms, presumably face an external finance premium, which is lower the stronger their financial position. For households, home equity is often a significant part of net worth. Certainly, households with low mortgage loan-to-value ratios can borrow on relatively favorable terms through home-equity lines of credit, with the equity in their home effectively serving as collateral. If the financial accelerator hypothesis is correct, changes in home values may affect household borrowing and spending by somewhat more than suggested by the conventional wealth effect because changes in homeowners' net worth also affect their external finance premiums and thus their costs of credit. If true, this hypothesis has various interesting implications. For example, unlike the standard view based on the wealth effect, this approach would suggest that the distribution of housing wealth across the population matters because the effect on aggregate consumption of a given decline in house prices is greater, the greater the fraction of consumers who begin with relatively low home equity. Another possible implication is that the structure of mortgage contracts may matter for consumption behavior. In countries like the United Kingdom, for example, where most mortgages have adjustable rates, changes in short-term interest rates (whether induced by monetary policy or some other factor) have an almost immediate effect on household cash flows. If household cash flows affect access to credit, then consumer spending may react relatively quickly. In an economy where most mortgages carry fixed rates, such as the United States, that channel of effect may be more muted. I do not think we know at this point whether, in the case of households, these effects are quantitatively significant in the aggregate. Certainly, these issues seem worthy of further study.

Monetary Policy and the Credit Channel
The ideas I have been discussing today have also been useful in understanding the nature of the monetary policy transmission process. Some evidence suggests that the influence of monetary policy on real variables is greater than can be explained by the traditional "cost-of-capital" channel, which holds that monetary policy affects borrowing, investment, and spending decisions solely through its effect on the level of market interest rates. This finding has led researchers to look for supplementary channels through which monetary policy may affect the economy. One such supplementary channel, the so-called credit channel, holds that monetary policy has additional effects because interest-rate decisions affect the cost and availability of credit by more than would be implied by the associated movement in risk-free interest rates, such as Treasury rates. The credit channel, in turn, has traditionally been broken down into two components or channels of policy influence: the balance-sheet channel and the bank-lending channel (Bernanke and Gertler, 1995). The balance-sheet channel of monetary policy is closely related to the idea of the financial accelerator that I have already discussed. That theory builds from the premise that changes in interest rates engineered by the central bank affect the values of the assets and the cash flows of potential borrowers and thus their creditworthiness, which in turn affects the external finance premium that borrowers face. For example, according to this view, a tightening of monetary policy that reduces the net worth and liquidity of borrowers would increase the effective cost of credit by more than the change in risk-free rates and thus would intensify the effect of the policy action.

In the interest of time I will confine the remainder of my remarks to the bank-lending channel. The theory of the bank-lending channel holds that monetary policy works in part by affecting the supply of loans offered by depository institutions. This concept is a cousin of the idea I proposed in my paper on the Great Depression, that the failures of banks during the 1930s destroyed "information capital" and thus reduced the effective supply of credit to borrowers. Alan Blinder and I adapted this general idea to show how, by affecting banks' loanable funds, monetary policy could influence the supply of intermediated credit (Bernanke and Blinder, 1988).

Historically, monetary policy did appear to affect the supply of bank loans (at any given level of interest rates). In the 1960s and 1970s, when reserve requirements were higher and more comprehensive than they are today, Federal Reserve open market operations that drained reserves from the banking system tended to force a contraction in deposits. Regulation Q, which capped interest rates payable on deposits, prevented banks from offsetting the decline in deposits by offering higher interest rates. Moreover, banks had limited alternatives to deposits as a funding source. Thus, monetary tightening typically resulted in a shrinking of banks' balance sheets and a diversion of funds away from the banking system, a phenomenon known as disintermediation. The extension of credit to bank-dependent borrowers, which included many firms as well as households, was consequently reduced, with implications for spending and economic activity.

Of course, much has changed in U.S. banking and financial markets since the 1960s and 1970s. Reserve requirements are lower and apply to a smaller share of deposits than in the past. Regulation Q is gone. And the capital markets have become deep, liquid, and easily accessible, either directly or indirectly, to almost all depository institutions. Although the traditional bank-lending channel may still be operative in economies that remain relatively more bank-dependent, as recent research has found for some European countries (Ehrmann and others, 2003), in the United States today it seems unlikely to be quantitatively important.

This is not to say, however, that financial intermediation no longer matters for monetary policy and the transmission of economic shocks. For example, although banks and other intermediaries no longer depend exclusively on insured deposits for funding, nondeposit sources of funding are likely to be relatively more expensive than deposits, reflecting the credit risks associated with uninsured lending (Stein, 1998). Moreover, the cost and availability of nondeposit funds for any given bank will depend on the perceived creditworthiness of the institution. Thus, the concerns of holders of uninsured bank liabilities about bank credit quality generate an external finance premium for banks that is similar to that faced by other borrowers. The external finance premium paid by banks is presumably reflected in turn in the cost and availability of funds to bank-dependent borrowers. Importantly, this way of casting the bank-lending channel unifies the financial accelerator and credit channel concepts, as the central mechanism of both is seen to be the external finance premium and its relationship to borrowers' balance sheets. The only difference is that the financial accelerator focuses on the ultimate borrowers--firms and households--whereas financial intermediaries are the relevant borrowers in the theory of the credit channel. By the way, the existence of loan sales and the originate-to-distribute model of bank lending does not fundamentally change this picture. Loan sales and similar activities are, in essence, another form of nondeposit financing, and the effective cost of this form of funding to the bank will generally depend on its perceived financial strength and resources (which may affect recourse and reinsurance arrangements with the loan purchasers, for example).

Recently, researchers have pursued a number of approaches in search of evidence of a distinct banking channel. For example, some researchers have focused on smaller banks, which may have fewer funding alternatives to deposits and whose customer base may consist disproportionately of bank-dependent borrowers (Kashyap and Stein, 2000). Of course, these days, even the smallest of banks has ready access to sources of funds other than retail deposits. Thus, even for the smallest banks, the source of any bank-lending channel remains the existence of a finance premium on marginal sources of (uninsured) nondeposit funding, rather than an absolute constraint on the quantity of available funding. Moreover, for the bank channel to affect economic activity, borrowers accustomed to relying on banks must be unable to turn to other lenders, at least not without some cost. For some business borrowers, particularly small business borrowers that rely on banking relationships, this scenario is plausible.4 But financial innovation and deregulation imply that borrowers in the market for a mortgage or consumer credit have numerous nonbank financing alternatives, blunting any direct impact of changes in bank lending. I will return to nonbank lending and its implications in a moment.

If relationship borrowing is the key, then--as pointed out in the paper at this conference by Black, Hancock, and Passmore--a bank with many such borrowers might defensively invest in deposit capacity, say, by increasing the number of branches. By actively seeking to finance a high share of loans with insured deposits, such a bank could shield its borrowers from the effects of increases in the nondeposit finance premium, whether the result of monetary policy or some other factor. Consistent with this idea, these authors find that banks that make a large share of their loans to small businesses also tend to have a high ratio of deposits to loans.

The recognition that, fundamentally, the bank-lending channel is based on changes in the quality of bank balance sheets naturally turns our attention to bank capital and its determinants (Van den Heuvel, 2002). Raising new capital on the open market can be difficult and costly for many banks, implying that, in the short run, capital is determined by earnings and changes in asset values. Changes in the value of capital, particularly when a bank's capital is not much higher than the level demanded by regulators or the market, potentially affects the bank's cost of funds. In conformity with this hypothesis, various studies have found evidence that loans provided by banks that are more capital-constrained seem more sensitive to changes in market interest rates than loans provided by highly capitalized banks.5 Moreover, changes in the financial condition of banks may play a role in cyclical developments. I have already mentioned the cases of Japan's "lost decade." Closer to home, some believe that the U.S. economy's recovery from the 1990-91 recession was delayed by "financial headwinds," which arose from regional shortages of bank capital (Bernanke and Lown, 1991).

One might view the idea that banks are somehow "special" in their ability to gather information and to screen and monitor borrowers as rather dated. Banks do continue to play a central role in credit markets; in particular, because of the burgeoning market for loan sales, banks originate considerably more loans than they keep on their books. Nevertheless, nonbank lenders have become increasingly important in many credit markets, and relatively few borrowers are restricted to banks as sources of credit. Of course, nonbank lenders do not have access to insured deposits. However, they can fund loans by borrowing on capital markets or by selling loans to securitizers. Does the rise of nonbank lenders make the bank-lending channel irrelevant?

I am not so sure that it does. Like banks, nonbank lenders have to raise funds in order to lend, and the cost at which they raise those funds will depend on their financial condition--their net worth, their leverage, and their liquidity, for example. Thus, nonbank lenders also face an external finance premium that presumably can be influenced by economic developments or monetary policy. The level of the premium they pay will in turn affect the rates that they can offer borrowers. Thus, the ideas underlying the bank-lending channel might reasonably extend to all private providers of credit. Further investigation of this possibility would be quite worthwhile.

Conclusion
I have taken you on a whirlwind tour of several decades of research on how variations in the financial condition of borrowers, whether arising from changes in monetary policy or from other forces, can affect short-term economic dynamics. The critical idea is that the cost of funds to borrowers depends inversely on their creditworthiness, as measured by indicators such as net worth and liquidity. Endogenous changes in creditworthiness may increase the persistence and amplitude of business cycles (the financial accelerator) and strengthen the influence of monetary policy (the credit channel). As I have noted today, what has been called the bank-lending channel--the idea that banks play a special role in the transmission of monetary policy--can be integrated into this same broad logical framework, if we focus on the link between the bank's financial condition and its cost of capital. Nonbank lenders may well be subject to the same forces.

Let me conclude by offering you best wishes for a stimulating and enjoyable last day of the conference. Policymakers and scholars both will benefit from your efforts.

References

Almeida, Heitor, Murillo Campello, and Crocker H. Liu (2006). "The Financial Accelerator: Evidence from International Housing Markets," Review of Finance, vol. 10 (September), pp. 1-32.

Aoki, Kosuki, James Proudman, and Gertjan Vlieghe (2002). "Houses as Collateral: Has the Link between House Prices and Consumption in the U.K. Changed?" (188 KB PDF) Economic Policy Review, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, May, pp. 163-77

-----------------------------------------------(2004). "House Prices, Consumption, and Monetary Policy: A Financial Accelerator Approach," Journal of Financial Intermediation, vol. 13 (October), pp. 414-35.

Avery, Robert B., and Katherine A. Samolyk (2004). "Bank Consolidation and the Provision of Banking Services: Small Commercial Loans," Journal of Financial Services Research, vol. 25 (April), pp. 291-325.

Bernanke, Ben S. (1983). "Non-Monetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression," American Economic Review, vol. 73 (June), pp. 257-76.

Bernanke, Ben S., and Alan S. Blinder (1988). "Credit, Money, and Aggregate Demand," American Economic Review, vol. 78, Papers and Proceedings of the 100th Annual Meeting of the American Economics Association, May, pp. 435-39.

Bernanke, Ben S., and Mark Gertler (1989). "Agency Costs, Net Worth, and Business Fluctuations," American Economic Review, vol. 79 (March), pp. 14-31.

--------------------------------------(1995). "Inside the Black Box: The Credit Channel of Monetary Policy Transmission," Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 9 (Fall), pp. 27-48.

Bernanke, Ben S., Mark Gertler, and Simon Gilchrist (1999). "The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business Cycle Framework," in Handbook of Macroeconomics, Volume 1C, Handbooks in Economics, vol. 15. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 1341-93.

Bernanke, Ben S., and Cara S. Lown (1991). "The Credit Crunch," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1991:2, pp. 205-39.

Black, Lamont, Diana Hancock, and Wayne Passmore (2007). "Bank Core Deposits and the Mitigation of Monetary Policy," unpublished paper, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, June.

Calomiris, Charles W., Charles P. Himmelberg, and Paul Wachtel (1995). "Commercial Paper, Corporate Finance and the Business Cycle: A Microeconomic Perspective," Carnegie-Rochester Series on Public Policy, vol. 42 (June), pp. 203-50.

Carlstrom, CharlesT., and Timothy S. Fuerst (2001). "Monetary Policy in a World without Perfect Capital Markets," Working Paper 0115, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

Carpenter, Robert E., Steven M. Fazzari, and Bruce C. Petersen (1998). "Financing Constraints and Inventory Investment: A Comparative Study with High-Frequency Panel Data," (265 KB PDF) Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 80 (December), pp. 513-19.

Ehrmann, Michael, Leonardo Gambacorta, Jorge Martinez-Pages, Patrick Sevestre, and Andreas Worms (2003). "Financial Systems and the Role of Banks in Monetary Policy Transmission in the Euro Area," in Ignazio Angeloni, Anil K Kashyap, and Benoit Mojon, eds., Monetary Policy Transmission in the Euro area: A Study by the Eurosystem Monetary Transmission Network,. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Fisher, Irving (1933). "The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions," Econometrica, vol. 1 (October), pp. 337-57.

Gambacorta, Leonardo (2005). "Inside the Bank Lending Channel," European Economic Review, vol. 49 (October), pp. 1737-59.

Gilchrist, Simon, and Charles Himmelberg (1999). "Investment, Fundamentals and Finance," in Ben S. Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg, eds. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1998. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

Iacoviello, Matteo (2005). "House Prices, Borrowing Constraints, and Monetary Policy in the Business Cycle," American Economic Review, vol. 95 (June), pp. 739-64.

Jensen, Michael C., and William H. Meckling (1976). "Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure," Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 3 (October), pp. 305-60.

Kashyap, Anil K, and Jeremy C. Stein (2000). "What Do a Million Observations on Banks Say about the Transmission of Monetary Policy?" American Economic Review, vol. 90 (June), pp. 407-28.

Kishan, Ruby P., and Timothy Opiela (2000). "Bank Size, Bank Capital, and the Bank Lending Channel," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 32 (February), pp. 121-41.

------------------------------- (2006). "Bank Capital and Loan Asymmetry in the Transmission of Monetary Policy," Journal of Banking and Finance, vol. 30 (January), pp. 259-85.

Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro, and John Moore (1997). "Credit Cycles," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 105 (April), pp. 211-48.

Levin, Andrew T., and Fabio M. Natalucci (2005). "The Magnitude and Cyclical Behavior of Financial Market Frictions," 2005 Meeting Papers 443, Society for Economic Dynamics.

Levin, Andrew T., Fabio M. Natalucci, and Egon Zakrajsek (2004). "The Magnitude and Cyclical Behavior of Financial Market Frictions," Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2004-70, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, December.

Stein, Jeremy C. (1998). "An Adverse-Selection Model of Bank Asset and Liability Management with Implications for the Transmission of Monetary Policy," RAND Journal of Economics, vol. 29 (Autumn), pp. 466-86.

Van den Heuvel, Skander (2002). "Does Bank Capital Matter for Monetary Transmission?" (100 KB PDF) Economic Policy Review, Federal Reserve Bank of New York (May), pp. 1-7.

Footnotes

1. Over the past two decades, an extensive theoretical literature has exploited the idea that borrowers' financial positions affect their external finance premiums and thus their overall cost of credit. See, for example, Bernanke and Gertler (1989), Kiyotaki and Moore (1997), Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist (1999), Carlstrom and Fuerst (2001), Aoki, Proudman and Vlieghe (2004), and Iacoviello (2005).

2. Calomiris, Himmelberg and Wachtel,(1995), Carpenter, Fazzari and Petersen (1998), and Gilchrist and Himmelberg (1999).

3. See Aoki, Proudman and Vlieghe (2002, 2004), Iacoviello (2005), and Almeida, Campello and Liu (2006).

4. In recent years, community banks appear to have become increasingly important in lending to small businesses (Avery and Samolyk, 2004).

5. Kishan and Opiela, (2000), Kishan and Opiela, (2006), and Gambacorta (2005).

[뉴스핌 베스트 기사]

사진
관세협상 쟁점…쌀·쇠고기·구글지도 [세종=뉴스핌] 최영수 선임기자 = 한미 관세협상이 막판까지 '진통'을 겪고 있다. 오는 8일 1일까지 관세 유예기한이 연장되면서 일단 3주간 시간을 벌었다. 하지만 이견을 좁히지 못한 쟁점이 여전히 남아 있어 앞으로의 협상도 난항이 예상된다. 수차례 협상에도 이견을 좁히지 못한 것은 결국 '비관세장벽' 때문이다. 특히 한국 측이 민감분야로 설정하고 있는 ▲쌀 시장 개방 ▲30개월 이상 쇠고기 수입 허용 ▲구글 정밀지도 반출 허용 등 3가지 쟁점이 분수령이 될 전망이다. ◆ '제조업 협력' 카드 제시했지만…美, 농축산물 개방까지 요구 미국 정부는 오는 8월 1일부터 한국에 대한 품목관세(25%)를 부과할 방침이라고 8일 밝혔다. 도널드 트럼프 대통령은 8일 오전 1시 20분(한국시간) 트루스소셜(Truth Social)을 통해 한국에 대한 상호관세율 및 발효일자 등이 포함된 서한을 공개했다고 밝혔다. 이는 지난 4월 2일 발표한 국가별 관세와 같은 수준이다. 협상 시한이 3주간 연장된 셈이다. 도널드 트럼프 미국 대통령 [사진=로이터 뉴스핌] 한국 정부는 앞서 미국 측에 '제조업 협력 로드맵'을 제시했지만, 이것만으로는 미국 측의 합의를 이끌어내지 못한 것으로 알려졌다. 한국 측이 농축산물 등 민감분야를 사수하면서 '제조업 협력' 카드만으로 협상을 진행해 왔지만, 결국 한계에 봉착한 것 아니냐는 분석이 나온다. 산업부는 "새 정부 출범 이후 짧은 시간동안 국익 최우선 원칙을 갖고 치열하게 협상에 임했으나 현실적으로 모든 이슈들에 대해 합의 도출까지 시간이 부족했다"고 밝혔다. ◆ 자동차·철강 품목관세 인하 vs 농·축산물 개방 '저울질' 한미 간 몇 차례 협상에도 진통을 겪고 있는 이유는 결국 미국 정부가 농축산물 시장까지 요구하고 있기 때문이다. 더불어 한국의 정밀지도를 구글에 허용해 달라는 요구 역시 한국 정부로서는 민감한 쟁점이어서 난항이 예상된다. 한국 정부의 목표는 이 같은 민감분야를 사수하면서 자동차·철강 품목관세를 경쟁국 대비 불리하지 않은 수준으로 인하하는 것이다. 여한구 산업통상자원부 통상교섭본부장은 지난 6일 협상 결과에 대해 "자동차와 철강 등 품목관세 철폐 또는 완화가 반드시 포함돼야 한다"고 못 박았다. 여한구 산업통상자원부 통상교섭본부장(오른쪽)과 제이미슨 그리어(Jamieson Greer) USTR 대표가 5일 오후(현지시간) 미국 워싱턴 D.C.에서 관세협상에 앞서 기념사진을 찍고 있다. [사진=산업통상자원부] 2025.07.06 dream@newspim.com 문제는 농업계와 소관부처(농림축산식품부)를 어떻게 설득하느냐다. 과거 정부도 쌀 시장 개방과 쇠고기 수입을 검토했다가 강한 저항에 부딪혀 보류한 바 있다. 정부 안팎에서는 품목관세를 완전히 철폐하는 조건이라면 농축산물 시장을 개방하는 것도 고려해 볼만하다는 분위기가 읽힌다. 산업부는 8일 미국 정부의 발표에 대해 "미국 측의 주된 관심사인 무역적자 해소를 위한 국내 제도 개선, 규제 합리화 등과 함께, 양국 간 제조업 르네상스 파트너십을 통해 핵심산업 도약의 기회로 활용할 계획"이라고 밝혔다. 이는 한국 측의 요구대로 자동차, 철강 등 품목관세를 원하는 수준으로 인하(철폐)될 경우, 미국 측이 요구하고 있는 비관세장벽 개선에 대해서도 전향적으로 검토할 수 있다는 뜻으로 해석된다. 결국 품목관세 철폐와 비관세장벽 개선 두 가지 요소를 놓고 얼마나 균형적이고 합리적이 수준으로 타결되느냐가 관건이 될 전망이다. 한국 정부가 '상호호혜적이고 균형적인 협상'을 기본 원칙으로 내세우는 것도 이 때문이다. 산업부는 "관세로 인한 불확실성을 조속히 해소하기 위해 남은 기간 동안 상호 호혜적인 협상결과 도출을 위해 협상에 박차를 가할 것"이라고 강조했다. dream@newspim.com 2025-07-08 11:38
사진
'어느덧 20살' 슈퍼주니어 [서울=뉴스핌] 오광수 문화전문기자 = 슈퍼주니어(SUPER JUNIOR, 에스엠엔터테인먼트 소속)가 8일 정규 12집 'Super Junior25'(슈퍼주니어 이오)로 컴백했다. 이번 앨범은 슈퍼주니어 데뷔 20주년을 기념하는 앨범이다. 총 9곡이 수록되어 있으며, 타이틀 곡은 'Express Mode'(익스프레스 모드)다. 'Express Mode'는 댄서블한 사운드와 중독적인 후렴구가 특징인 업템포 클럽 팝 곡으로, 가사에는 현재에 멈추지 않고 다음 목표를 향해 나아가고자 하는 패기 넘치는 태도를 담았다. 어느덧 20년이 된 슈퍼주니어가 컴백을 기념하여 일문일답을 진행했다. [서울=뉴스핌] 오광수 문화전문기자 = 데뷔 20주년을 맞은 슈퍼주니어.[사진= SM엔터테인먼트] 2025.07.08 oks34@newspim.com 1. 드디어 정규 12집, 데뷔 20주년 기념 앨범이 발매되는 소감은?- 이특: 슈퍼주니어가 20년을 함께했다. 저 역시 너무나 놀라운 시간이었는데, 이번 앨범을 시작으로 앞으로 더욱 놀라운 시간을 만들어 가도록 하겠다.- 시원: 믿기지 않을 만큼 긴 시간이었던 것 같다. 하지만 그만큼 값진 시간이었다. 지금까지 함께해 준 멤버들, 스태프들, 그리고 무엇보다 변함없이 곁을 지켜준 팬분들 덕분에 이 앨범이 더욱 의미 있게 완성될 수 있었던 것 같아 감사하다. 2. 앨범명도 특별하다. 'Super Junior05'에서 'Super Junior25'가 됐는데, 슈퍼주니어에게 있어 가장 많이 바뀐 것과 그래도 여전히 바뀌지 않은 것은 무엇인지?- 희철: 가장 많이 바뀐 것은 저의 외모. 이번 앨범 준비하면서 다이어트도 하고 식단도 했는데… 여전히 바뀌지 않은 것은 이특, 은혁의 동안력과 몸무게. 둘을 보며 좋은 자극을 많이 받는다.- 예성: 정신 연령? ㅎㅎ 우리는 아직 20대 같다.- 려욱: 멤버들의 입담과 '티키타카'는 변함없는 것 같다. 대본 없이 우리끼리 카메라 하나 두고도 콘텐츠 백만 개는 나올 것 같다. [서울=뉴스핌] 오광수 문화전문기자 = 데뷔 20주년을 맞은 슈퍼주니어. [사진= SM엔터테인먼트] 2025.07.08 oks34@newspim.com 3. '히트곡 부자'로 유명한 만큼 타이틀 곡을 정하면서도 많은 고민이 있었을 것 같은데, 'Express Mode'가 선정된 이유가 있다면?- 예성: 다른 좋은 곡들도 많았지만 이 노래가 가장 '타이틀 곡' 같다고 느껴졌다.- 신동: 저희는 항상 새로운 걸 시도하려고 하지 않나, 이번에도 고민 진짜 많이 했다. 그런데 'Express Mode'를 듣자마자 다들 "이거다!" 싶었다. 슈퍼주니어다운 에너지와 재치, 그리고 요즘 감성까지 딱 잘 버무려진 곡이라, 들으면 그냥 바로 타이틀! 하는 느낌이다.- 은혁: 20주년이라는 숫자와 지금의 위치에 안주하지 않고 앞으로도 한발 한발 더 나아가겠다는 의미도 있고, 음악과 퍼포먼스도 우리를 잘 표현할 수 있다는 생각이 들었다.- 려욱: 데모 들을 때만 해도 'Haircut'에 한 표를 던졌던 나였지만, 녹음을 하고 보니 'Express Mode'가 우리의 에너지를 잘 담고 있었고 퍼포먼스까지 멋지게 보여줄 수 있을 거라 생각돼서 인정하게 됐다. 4. 최근 일상에서 나를 제일 'Express Mode'로 설레게 혹은 달리게 만드는 것은?- 희철: 반려견 기복이 산책.(웃음) 기복이 활동량이 상당해서 하루에 몇 번씩 산책을 하는데 이리 뛰고, 저리 뛰고 아주 난리도 아니다. 기복이가 저를 미친 듯이 달리게 만든다.- 예성: E.L.F.들과 어서 만나고 싶다는 생각이 저를 'Express Mode'로 달리게 만든다. 우리 더 가까워지자!- 려욱: 노래 연습을 꾸준히 하고 있다. E.L.F.들에게 멋진 노래를 들려주고 싶고, 하루빨리 콘서트로 보답하고 싶은 마음이다.- 규현: 퇴근 후 접속하는 '33 원정대'.(웃음) 오랜만에 빠지게 된 게임이다. [서울=뉴스핌] 오광수 문화전문기자 = 데뷔 20주년을 맞은 슈퍼주니어. [사진= SM엔터테인먼트] 2025.07.08 oks34@newspim.com 5. 타이틀 곡 'Express Mode' 퍼포먼스, 준비하면서 어렵지는 않았는지?- 예성: 디스크 때문에 조금 고생했지만 안무가 좋아서 더 열심히 했다.- 신동: 솔직히… 좀 힘들었다. 하하! 퍼포먼스가 진짜 'Express Mode'로 달려야 해서, 예전처럼 체력으로만 밀어붙이긴 어렵더라. 대신 디테일한 표현, 팀워크를 더 살리려고 노력했다. 근데 또 무대 올라가면 신기하게 힘이 난다. E.L.F. 앞이라 그런가 보다.- 은혁: 멤버들 모두 즐거운 분위기 속에서 열심히 잘 준비했다. 그래서 그런지 전혀 어렵지 않았다.(웃음) 6. 앨범 콘셉트인 'SUPER AWARDS'처럼 서로에게 주고 싶은 상 이름을 직접 정해본다면?- 신동: 은혁이한테 '몸이 한 개로 부족했상'을 주고 싶다. 안무 짜랴, 디렉팅 보랴, 촬영 챙기랴… 진짜 슈퍼 히어로다. 그리고 희철이 형한테는 '말은 많았지만 행동도 많았상', 은근히 뒤에서 멤버들 챙기고 조용히 마음 써준 거 다 알고 있다. 나머지 멤버들에겐? '아직도 이렇게 잘생겼상' 드린다. 왜냐면… 정말 아직도 잘생겼으니까.(웃음)- 려욱: '너네가 짱이야 상' 7. 지난 20주년을 돌아보며 가장 기억에 남는 순간은 언제인지?- 시원: 나이가 드는지 데뷔 무대가 갑자기 기억이 난다.- 려욱: 데뷔했던 순간이 제일 마음에 와 닿는다. 무중력 상태에서 우주를 떠다니듯 춤추고 노래했던 기억이 난다. 꺼진 마이크에 크게 목놓아 부른 'Twins'는 아직도 잊지 못한다.- 규현: 'SUPER SHOW' 투어를 다닐 때인 것 같다. 어느새 너무 오랜 시간 공연을 해와서 기억도 뒤죽박죽이긴 하지만 역시 남는 건 벅차게 느꼈던 공연 순간의 감동이다. [서울=뉴스핌] 오광수 문화전문기자 = 데뷔 20주년을 맞은 슈퍼주니어. [사진= SM엔터테인먼트] 2025.07.08 oks34@newspim.com 8. 슈퍼주니어하면 콘서트도 빼놓을 수 없는데, 'SUPER SHOW 10' 투어가 곧 시작된다. 200회 공연도 앞두고 있는데, 앞으로 새롭게 세워보고 싶은 기록이 있다면?- 이특: 숫자에 대한 기록이라면 300회, 400회, 계속해서 새로운 숫자를 써 나가는 것이 목표다. 그리고 시간이 더 흘렀을 때 'SUPER SHOW'가 더욱 다양한 콘텐츠로 새롭게 재탄생하기를 바라본다.- 예성: 기록에 대해선 큰 생각은 없지만 하다 보니 200회 공연이 되다니 신기하다. 벌써 우리가 이렇게 오래 공연을 하고 있다니!- 려욱: 300회까지 가면 좋을 것 같다. 슈퍼주니어 멤버들과 관객들과 함께하는 시간들이 쌓일수록 그 횟수가 어떻든 행복할 것 같다.- 규현: 가보지 못했던 곳들도 갈 수 있었으면 좋겠다. 전 세계에 E.L.F.가 살게 되는 기록도 꿈꿔본다! 9. 슈퍼주니어에게 붙는 수식어가 많은데, 제일 마음에 드는 것은? 앞으로 어떤 수식어를 더 만들어가고 싶은지?- 은혁: 너무 거창한 수식어들은 솔직히 좀 민망하고 쑥스러운 것 같다. 그냥… '수식어가 필요 없는 그룹' 슈퍼주니어라는 표현이 가장 좋지 않을까?- 려욱: '한류 광개토대왕'이 제일 좋다. 어렸을 때 광개토대왕을 좋아해서 그런지 몰라도… 내 마음에 콕 박힌다. 10. 이번 앨범으로 이루고 싶은 목표는?- 희철: 이제 우리가 무슨 바라는 목표가 있겠나… 무탈히 즐겁게 활동 잘 마치길 바란다. 사랑한다 멤버들아!! 건강하자!!- 예성: 활동 끝까지 무사히 잘 해내고 싶다. 즐겁고 행복하게 마무리하고 싶은 마음이다.- 시원: 이번 앨범은 단순한 앨범이 아니라, 저희가 걸어온 20년의 시간과 그 안에 담긴 이야기들을 다음 세대에게 전하고 싶은 마음이 크다. 이 여정이 누군가에겐 시작점의 작은 용기나 희망이 되고, 후배들에게는 '이렇게 꾸준히, 진심으로 해 나가면 가능하구나'라는 좋은 선례가 되었으면 한다. 11. 20년 동안 슈퍼주니어를 지켜준 E.L.F.에게 한 마디- 이특: 한결같이 우리를 응원해주고 사랑해주는 E.L.F.! 이제는 우리가 받았던 사랑을 돌려주고, 그 사랑에 보답하기 위해 노력하겠다. 늘 고맙고 사랑한다!- 동해: E.L.F.가 없었다면 모든 것이 불가능이라고 말하고 싶다. 아무리 꽃이 예뻐도 하늘에 햇빛이 없고 물을 주지 않으면 시들듯이, 우리는 E.L.F.라는 존재가 없으면 내일 당장 시들어 버릴 거다. E.L.F.에게 너무 고맙고 앞으로도 잘 부탁한다. 진심으로 사랑해!- 려욱: 우리와 함께해 준 영원한 친구 E.L.F.들 정말 고마워. 함께 울고 웃던 시간들이 너무 소중하다. 내 인생에 큰 선물이고 오래오래 기억하고 싶어. 20주년 너무 감사하고 우리 앞으로 함께하자. 사랑해. 슈퍼주니어는 8월부터 데뷔 20주년 기념 투어 'SUPER SHOW 10'(슈퍼쇼 10)에 돌입한다. 투어의 막을 올리는 서울 공연은 8월 22~24일 올림픽공원 KSPO DOME에서 개최된다. 또한 서울 공연을 시작으로 9월 홍콩, 자카르타, 10월 마닐라, 멕시코시티, 몬테레이, 리마, 산티아고, 11월 타이베이, 방콕, 12월 나고야, 2026년 1월 싱가포르, 마카오, 쿠알라룸푸르, 가오슝, 3월 사이타마까지 슈퍼주니어는 전 세계 16개 지역에서 투어를 이어가며 '레전드 공연킹'다운 면모를 보여주고 20주년을 화려하게 마무리할 전망이다. oks34@newspim.com 2025-07-08 13:40
안다쇼핑
Top으로 이동